Nick Rowe on Twitter earlier today:
Suppose no one know about the size of the peanut harvest until the following period. In this case, the central bank, which we will assume can completely control the price of peanuts for the time being, is not culpable for the recession that occurs because the price of peanuts is too low. The central bank could not have known that the price level (of peanuts) at which output remained at potential was higher than they otherwise thought, so they cannot be blamed for the recession that ensues.
If, on a slightly different note, the central bank faces a delay in policy implementation, it may not be able to act quickly enough to prevent a recession; they can raise the target price with a delay, but there will still be a recession in the meantime and the central bank is not culpable.
Alternatively, assume that the central bank knows about the bad harvest in real time and doesn't face a policy lag, but, for some reason, is unable to set the price of peanuts any higher. In this case, the central bank can't be blamed either -- there is nothing it can do to prevent it from happening, so the correct culprit for the recession is the bad peanut harvest.
Generally, assuming there are no significant lags in information or implementation, the central bank would be to blame for not preventing the recession. The only time that the blame really shouldn't fall on a central bank is when it can't control the price (of peanuts) -- in this case, central bank impotence is to blame for the recession, not actions taken by the central bank.
With that aside, now we can go about determining when central banks are impotent.
If [a] central bank targeted the price of peanuts, would we blame recessions on bad peanut harvests? Or blame [the] central bank for not raising [the] target price?It depends. It depends on how quickly the central bank finds out about the bad peanut harvest, how quickly the new policy can be enacted, and how effectively the central bank can control the price of peanuts.
Suppose no one know about the size of the peanut harvest until the following period. In this case, the central bank, which we will assume can completely control the price of peanuts for the time being, is not culpable for the recession that occurs because the price of peanuts is too low. The central bank could not have known that the price level (of peanuts) at which output remained at potential was higher than they otherwise thought, so they cannot be blamed for the recession that ensues.
If, on a slightly different note, the central bank faces a delay in policy implementation, it may not be able to act quickly enough to prevent a recession; they can raise the target price with a delay, but there will still be a recession in the meantime and the central bank is not culpable.
Alternatively, assume that the central bank knows about the bad harvest in real time and doesn't face a policy lag, but, for some reason, is unable to set the price of peanuts any higher. In this case, the central bank can't be blamed either -- there is nothing it can do to prevent it from happening, so the correct culprit for the recession is the bad peanut harvest.
Generally, assuming there are no significant lags in information or implementation, the central bank would be to blame for not preventing the recession. The only time that the blame really shouldn't fall on a central bank is when it can't control the price (of peanuts) -- in this case, central bank impotence is to blame for the recession, not actions taken by the central bank.
With that aside, now we can go about determining when central banks are impotent.